top of page

Rory Sutherland: Solving Commercial Challenges Through Human Irrationality and Behavioral Science

  • ankitmorajkar
  • Jul 3
  • 29 min read

Updated: Aug 22

ree

This post is primarily intended for my own reference, so I can revisit these ideas. If you’ve stumbled upon it, you’re welcome to read along. None of the content here is original writing — it is entirely AI-generated.


My prompt to GPT 5 — “Give me a deep research prompt to comprehensively gather all Case Studies, Examples, and Anecdotes from Rory Sutherland”


GPT 5 Output fed into Gemini Deep Research 2.5 Flash — “Act as a meticulous researcher and compile a comprehensive, thematically organized collection of all case studies, real-world examples, metaphors, and anecdotes shared by Rory Sutherland across his books (including Alchemy), Ogilvy columns, keynote speeches, interviews, and podcasts. For each example, clearly state the original source, the full context in which it was shared, the behavioral science or marketing principle it illustrates, the lesson he intended to convey, and any notable quotes. Where possible, connect recurring anecdotes across different sources, highlight variations in how he tells them, and identify overarching themes and patterns in his storytelling style.”


Gemini Output —


1. The Alchemy of Human Behavior


Brief Introduction to Rory Sutherland


ree

Rory Sutherland is a distinguished figure in the advertising and behavioral science landscape, serving as the Vice-Chairman of Ogilvy UK and co-founder of its Behavioural Science Practice. His career trajectory is notably unconventional, having transitioned from a classics teacher to a leading light in the advertising industry. This diverse background underpins his unique approach to marketing and human behavior, allowing him to challenge conventional wisdom with both intellectual rigor and engaging wit.


Sutherland is a prolific communicator of his ideas. He is the author of influential books such as “Alchemy: The Surprising Power of Ideas That Don’t Make Sense” and “Rory Sutherland: The Wiki Man,” a collection of his columns, interviews, and blog posts. Beyond his books, he regularly contributes “The Wiki Man” column to The Spectator and has delivered widely viewed TED Talks, accumulating millions of views. Through these various platforms, Sutherland has become a prominent champion of behavioral economics, advocating for its application in understanding and influencing human decisions.


Sutherland’s Central Thesis: The Surprising Power of Ideas That Don’t Make Sense


At the heart of Sutherland’s philosophy lies the assertion that truly impactful ideas often emerge from seemingly irrational or illogical premises. He posits that what appears nonsensical from a purely rational standpoint can, when viewed through a psychological lens, reveal a profound “psycho-logic” that drives human action. This perspective fundamentally challenges the prevailing economic model that assumes individuals are rational actors making decisions based solely on objective evidence.


A core observation consistently articulated by Sutherland is the “physical fallacy.” This refers to an ingrained human and institutional bias to address problems with tangible, material solutions (“stuff”) rather than psychological ones (“grey matter”). This bias is deeply rooted, leading to a perception that creating intangible value is somehow “cheating” or less legitimate than physical creation. The broader implication of this observation is that many societal and business challenges are misdiagnosed and subsequently misaddressed because the underlying human irrationality and subjective experience are either ignored or significantly undervalued. This adherence to what Sutherland often terms the “dumber assumptions of Basic Economics 101” leads to misdirected efforts and missed opportunities for more effective, less resource-intensive solutions.


His philosophy is perhaps best encapsulated in these verifiable quotes:


“Engineers, medical people, scientific people, have an obsession with solving the problems of reality, when actually… once you reach a basic level of wealth in society, most problems are actually problems of perception.”


“It is much easier to be fired for being illogical than it is for being unimaginative. The fatal issue is that logic always gets you to exactly the same place as your competitors.”


“Not everything that makes sense works, and not everything that works makes sense.”


“When you demand logic, you pay a hidden price: you destroy magic.”


“The trouble with market research is that people don’t think what they feel, they don’t say what they think, and they don’t do what they say.”


2. Foundational Behavioral Science Principles in Sutherland’s Work


Sutherland’s extensive body of work consistently highlights several key behavioral science principles that challenge conventional wisdom and offer alternative pathways to problem-solving. These principles form the bedrock of his “alchemy” — the ability to create disproportionate value from seemingly illogical ideas.


Perception & Subjective Value


Sutherland frequently emphasizes that perceived value holds primacy over objective reality. He contends that “all value is perceived value” and that human perception is inherently “leaky,” meaning it is susceptible to influence from various cues beyond the intrinsic qualities of a product or service. This perspective suggests that the context and framing of an offering can dramatically alter its perceived worth, often overriding its objective attributes.


This observation implies a non-linearity in value creation. Beyond a certain point, efforts to improve objective quality yield diminishing returns. Instead, focusing on how something is perceived can generate immense value with minimal material cost. This suggests that marketing transcends mere information conveyance; it functions as a crucial value creation mechanism by shaping perception, a role often undervalued by traditional economic models. This directly contradicts the simplistic assumptions of basic economics, which often fail to account for the powerful, subjective lens through which humans experience the world.


Framing & Context


The way choices are presented and the surrounding environment profoundly influence human decisions. Sutherland illustrates that a slight change in wording or the broader context can dramatically shift behavior and alter the perceived value of an offering. This principle underscores that human decision-making is not purely rational but is heavily dependent on the psychological architecture of the choice environment.


The Power of Small Interventions


A recurring theme in Sutherland’s work is the disproportionate impact that minor, often counter-intuitive, changes can have. He consistently demonstrates that “small changes can solve huge problems”. These “psycho-logical” solutions, often inexpensive, can prove far more effective than large, costly engineering fixes.


This observation points to an institutional bias against “small stuff.” Large organizations and individuals in positions of power often gravitate towards “big important, and most of all, expensive solutions” for significant problems, frequently leading to wasted resources. This tendency stems from a “sense of self-aggrandizement” and a systemic lack of individuals who possess immense influence but operate without large budgets. This institutional inertia means that highly effective, low-cost behavioral solutions are frequently overlooked or dismissed because they do not align with the prevailing “big budget, big solution” paradigm.


The Logic of the Irrational


Sutherland argues that what appears irrational from a purely logical or economic standpoint often makes perfect sense when viewed through a psychological lens. He likens human behavior not to Newtonian physics, which assumes predictable, linear cause-and-effect, but rather to weather forecasting — complex, adaptive, yet ultimately predictable to a degree. This perspective encourages looking beyond superficial logic to uncover the deeper, often unconscious, motivations driving human action.


Signaling & Commitment Devices


Actions, investments, and visible cues, even those that seem wasteful, can serve crucial signaling functions. Sutherland explains that these “costly signals” demonstrate commitment, quality, or trustworthiness in ways that objective metrics alone often cannot.


This analysis reveals a hidden economic function of apparent waste. Traditional economic models often view “waste” as inefficiency to be eliminated. This “costly signaling” generates intangible value that influences market behavior and builds trust. The implication is that a relentless pursuit of purely numerical “efficiency” can inadvertently erode crucial psychological value and trust, potentially leading to suboptimal or “crappy outcomes”.


Satisficing vs. Maximizing


Individuals rarely engage in “maximizing” behavior by exhaustively comparing every available option to find the absolute best. Instead, they commonly “satisfice,” choosing the first “good enough” solution that meets their criteria. This strategy effectively reduces decision-making effort and mitigates risk.


This observation highlights the underestimated power of risk aversion in consumer choice. While maximizing implies striving for the best possible outcome, satisficing is frequently driven by a desire to minimize the worst-case scenario. Consumers often pay a premium for established brands not because those brands are objectively superior, but because they are “less likely to be terrible”. This underscores that certainty and risk reduction are often more valuable to consumers than marginal gains in objective quality, a factor frequently overlooked by market research that focuses on consumers’ stated desire to be “maximizers”.


Bias Towards Tangible Solutions


There is an innate human and institutional preference for addressing problems with physical infrastructure or material goods (“stuff”) rather than with psychological interventions (“grey matter”). This bias persists even when psychological solutions are demonstrably more effective, efficient, or environmentally friendly.


Friction & Information Overload


While often perceived as negative, friction can sometimes yield hidden benefits, such as reducing superfluous communication. Conversely, an abundance of choice can overwhelm individuals, leading to decision paralysis or suboptimal choices — a phenomenon known as the “paradox of choice”. This suggests that carefully managed constraints can enhance user experience and decision quality.


Reverse Benchmarking


Sutherland champions a strategic approach he terms “reverse benchmarking.” Instead of merely copying the best practices of market leaders, this strategy involves identifying areas where competitors perform poorly or neglect customer needs, and then excelling in those specific areas.


This approach uncovers a strategic blind spot in conventional business wisdom. “Benchmarking,” the practice of emulating industry leaders, is a widespread business practice, often justified by economic theory and ease of measurement. However, this can lead to “over-served markets” and stifle genuine innovation. “Reverse benchmarking,” by contrast, unearths “hidden value” and “psychological gaps” that conventional, “faux-rational” approaches miss. This suggests that focusing on “what do they do badly” can lead to disproportionate gains and true differentiation, fostering innovation often in areas neglected by the “arithmocracy” that prioritizes easily quantifiable metrics.


4. Detailed Case Studies, Examples, and Anecdotes


Rory Sutherland’s arguments are powerfully brought to life through a rich tapestry of real-world examples, each meticulously chosen to illustrate the nuances of human behavior and the limitations of purely rational approaches. This section delves into these prominent illustrations, providing their context, the core observations they reveal, and the behavioral science principles they embody.


Eurostar Wi-Fi vs. Speed


ree

A foundational example in Sutherland’s talks is the case of Eurostar’s investment in reducing travel time between London and Paris. The company spent a staggering £6 billion to shorten the journey by 40 minutes. Sutherland’s counter-proposal, offered at a tiny fraction of that cost (0.01% of £6 billion), was simply to install free Wi-Fi on the existing trains. His argument was that this intervention would make the journey significantly more enjoyable, effectively reducing the perceived travel time, to the point where passengers might even “ask for the trains to be slowed down”. This serves as his “oft-cited example” of the “physical fallacy”.


This illustration highlights a fundamental disconnect between engineering solutions and human experience. It reveals how engineers and policymakers often prioritize objective, measurable improvements (like speed) over subjective, experiential ones (like enjoyment). The “physical fallacy” leads to a massive misallocation of resources because it fails to recognize that human well-being is not solely a function of physical efficiency. The implication is that effective problem-solving requires a shift from purely technical optimization to a holistic understanding of human needs and perceptions, where psychological interventions can often yield superior results at a fraction of the cost.


Electronic Cigarette / Smoking at Parties


ree

In his Perspective is Everything TED Talk, Sutherland recounts how, after smoking bans in the UK, drinks parties became less enjoyable for him. He realized that smoking provided a social function: “If you stand and stare out of the window on your own, you’re an antisocial, friendless idiot. If you stand and stare out of the window on your own with a cigarette, you’re a fucking philosopher”. This anecdote powerfully illustrates the principle of reframing and social signaling. The same physical activity (standing alone) is perceived entirely differently based on a small contextual cue (the cigarette), highlighting how perceived identity and social framing profoundly influence an experience. The profound lesson is that “The power of reframing things cannot be overstated”.


Pensioners vs. Young Unemployed


ree

Continuing the theme of reframing, Sutherland contrasts the reported happiness levels of pensioners and the young unemployed. Both groups, he notes, share similar objective circumstances of having excess time and limited money. However, pensioners are generally happier, while the unemployed often experience depression. The behavioral principle at play is perceived choice and agency. The pensioners perceive their state as a chosen retirement, whereas the unemployed feel their situation has been thrust upon them. This difference in perceived control fundamentally alters their happiness. Sutherland humorously points out that the upper-middle classes in England have effectively “re-branded” unemployment as “a year off,” further demonstrating the power of psychological framing.


Stripy Toothpaste


ree

Why do consumers prefer stripy toothpaste over plain, functionally identical alternatives? As explored in Alchemy and The Knowledge Project podcast, the preference for stripes illustrates the power of aesthetics and perceived efficacy. The visual appeal and the subtle suggestion of multiple benefits (e.g., fresh breath and whitening) conveyed by the stripes drive preference, demonstrating that seemingly trivial aesthetic features can outweigh purely functional considerations.


Scotland’s Speeding Smileys


ree

Sutherland points to the effectiveness of simple behavioral nudges through the example of speed signs in Scotland that display a smiley or sad face depending on a driver’s speed. These non-punitive “smiley/sad faces” have been shown to be twice as effective at preventing road accidents as traditional speed cameras, despite lacking the direct threat of punishment. This demonstrates the potent influence of immediate, non-punitive feedback on human behavior.


This phenomenon reveals the efficacy of social feedback over coercion. It suggests that human behavior is often more responsive to subtle social cues and immediate, non-judgmental feedback than to direct threats or punitive measures. Compliance can be achieved through positive reinforcement and a sense of “being seen” and acknowledged, rather than solely through fear of retribution. This has broad implications for policy design, advocating for a shift from “stick” to “nudge” approaches, and recognizing the intrinsic human desire for social approval and self-correction.


Branded Painkillers / Car Wash Effect


ree

These examples illustrate the pervasive influence of perception on subjective experience and even physiological outcomes. Sutherland notes that people often feel their car drives better after a car wash. Similarly, branded painkillers are observed to be literally more effective than their generic counterparts.


These phenomena underscore that perception is “leaky” and that “all value is perceived value”. The perceived quality or efficacy of something can be profoundly influenced by superficial cues or branding, leading to a real physiological or psychological effect, often akin to the placebo effect. This reveals the tangible impact of intangible beliefs. The human mind can translate subjective beliefs — such as “this brand is better” or “my car is cleaner” — into measurable, objective outcomes, like reduced pain or improved driving perception. This highlights the profound influence of the placebo effect and the power of branding beyond mere information conveyance. It implies that investing in “intangible value” (e.g., brand reputation, aesthetic design, overall experience) can yield “real” benefits that are often overlooked by purely rational cost-benefit analyses.


Fredrick the Great & Potatoes


ree

This historical anecdote demonstrates the strategic use of psychological principles to overcome resistance to change. Fredrick the Great faced a challenge in convincing his subjects to adopt potatoes as a staple crop, as they initially resisted eating them. His solution was not to force consumption or provide rational arguments for their nutritional value. Instead, he cleverly rebranded potatoes as “exclusive to the Royals,” making them a forbidden fruit. This created a sense of desirability and status, leading people to want what was perceived as exclusive or difficult to obtain.


This illustrates the strategic use of scarcity and exclusivity to drive adoption. It shows that direct persuasion — simply telling people something is good for them — can be less effective than indirect psychological manipulation that taps into human desires for status and what is perceived as rare. Human desire is often driven more by social signals and perceived status than by pure utility. This principle is widely applicable in marketing and product launch strategies, where initial scarcity or a premium price point can create a halo effect that drives demand and desirability.


Two Dishwashers


In “Is Everything BS?”, Sutherland presents the seemingly absurd idea of owning two dishwashers. The non-obvious solution is that it eliminates the need to unload the dishwasher, as one can always be loading while the other is being used. This creative solution re-frames the problem from optimizing dishwashing efficiency to eliminating a common pain point (unloading). He notes, “What’s weird is that this occurs to absolutely nobody in advance. It is absolutely obvious in retrospect, but it’s completely nonobvious in advance,” highlighting the value of re-framing problems beyond their initial constraints.


Electrifying Homes in Ireland


ree

The decades-long process of persuading people to electrify their homes in Ireland serves as another example of overcoming ingrained habits. Sutherland recounts how it required creative persuasion, including a local priest being given whiskey to mention his enjoyment of electricity in sermons. This highlights that rational arguments alone are insufficient; overcoming psychological inertia and the reluctance to adopt behaviors that “marks them out as unusual” often requires leveraging social influence and creative interventions.


Lydmar Hotel Elevator Music


ree

The Lydmar Hotel in Stockholm provides a simple yet elegant example of how small interventions can significantly enhance customer experience. This hotel allows guests to choose their own elevator music. This seemingly trivial, inexpensive intervention makes customers’ hotel stays more enjoyable by providing a sense of control and personalization. Sutherland highlights this as a “very, very small” detail that creates a lasting positive experience.


This phenomenon demonstrates the amplifying effect of micro-empowerment on customer satisfaction. It reinforces the idea that granting even a trivial amount of control to users can significantly enhance their overall experience. The actual


impact of choosing elevator music on the journey itself is minimal, but the feeling of agency and personalization is powerful. This suggests that businesses should actively seek opportunities to offer small, low-cost choices that empower customers, rather than focusing solely on large-scale functional improvements. The emphasis shifts to optimizing the experience of a service, not just its objective delivery.


Airport Security and Liquids


ree

Sutherland discusses the persistent problem of people attempting to carry liquids through airport security, noting that the primary issue is the size of the container, not necessarily the malicious intent of the traveler. This regulatory approach creates significant backlogs and passenger annoyance. He observes that this challenge is typically framed as an engineering problem, leading to calls for more X-ray lanes, rather than a behavioral one. Sutherland advocates for changing behavior over changing reality, positioning this as another instance of the “physical fallacy”.


This scenario highlights the default institutional preference for “hard” over “soft” solutions. It reveals a systemic tendency within public sector and large organizations to default to expensive, physical infrastructure solutions, even when the root cause of a problem is fundamentally behavioral. The “physical fallacy” is not merely an individual bias but an institutional one, often driven by a perception that “intangible means” are somehow “cheating” or less legitimate. This leads to inefficient and often ineffective solutions, as the underlying human element is overlooked. The implication is that adopting a behavioral lens could unlock significant efficiencies and lead to better outcomes in public policy and large-scale operational challenges.


Apple Products & Steve Jobs


Apple products are frequently cited as exemplars of design and user experience, yet Sutherland points out that they are not always objectively superior in terms of raw technical specifications like “clock speed” or “processor power” compared to competitors. The success of Apple, he argues, can be attributed to Steve Jobs’s focus on the “loveliness of the interface and the joy that results from using it,” thereby creating “psychological value” through intangible attributes. This demonstrates that beyond a certain point, objective improvements yield diminishing returns, and subjective experience becomes paramount.


This observation suggests a shifting frontier of value creation from utility to experience. In mature markets, competitive advantage increasingly moves beyond purely functional attributes to emotional and experiential ones. Apple’s triumph was not achieved by being “objectively better” in every technical specification, but by being “subjectively better” in terms of user delight and aesthetic appeal. This implies that businesses need to transcend a purely utilitarian view of their products and services and invest in the “intangible value” that resonates emotionally with consumers. Sutherland emphasizes that this approach to value creation is also “the most environmentally friendly way of creating value” , as it does not require additional material resources.


Restaurant Experience (Food vs. Context)


Drawing on the ideas of Ludwig von Mises, Sutherland argues against a rigid distinction between the value created by a chef and that created by a cleaner in a restaurant. He illustrates this by imagining Michelin-starred food served in a restaurant that “smells slightly of sewage” or with a single misaligned fork.


The core observation is that the enjoyment and perceived value of a meal are a “product” (in a mathematical sense, implying multiplication) of both the intrinsic food quality and the context in which it is consumed. A poor contextual element can completely negate the value of even the highest quality food. As Sutherland states, “the taste of the food will be affected by the decor of the restaurant”. This highlights the multiplicative nature of experience value. A “zero” in any critical contextual element — such as hygiene, comfort, or service — can reduce the entire experience to zero, irrespective of the quality of other components. This implies that businesses must meticulously address all “prongs of the fork” in their customer experience. Neglecting seemingly minor contextual factors can undermine significant investments in core product quality, as the overall perception is a holistic, interconnected sum.


Abandoned Service Station / Asda Incident


ree

Sutherland recounts driving past an unlit service station that appeared closed, only to find out later it was open but the last staff member forgot to turn on the lights. He contrasts the potential £1,000 loss in takings from this oversight with an 80p theft. This real-world example demonstrates the prioritization of preventing small, measurable losses while ignoring much larger, unmeasured losses due to poor customer experience or signaling.


Bankrupt Restaurant with Smoked Glass Windows


ree

A highly acclaimed London restaurant went bankrupt, and Sutherland attributes its failure partly to its smoked glass windows, which made it appear closed. This illustrates the principle of signaling and perceived accessibility. Even with excellent food, creating an unwelcoming or seemingly closed impression can be fatal, as it discourages potential customers.


Fish and Chip Shop Not Answering the Phone


Sutherland describes trying to call a fish and chip shop to confirm if it was open but receiving no answer, despite seeing a queue outside. The shop’s explanation was, “Oh, we don’t answer the phone when we are busy.” Sutherland labels not answering the phone a “heinous offence,” arguing that the telephone is a critical technology for bridging interest and transaction. This practice stems from a flawed perception of phone answering as a mere cost rather than a vital component of business conduct, leading to significant lost sales


London Black Cab Drivers & “The Knowledge”


ree


The rigorous “Knowledge” training, a three-to-four-year process for London black cab drivers to memorize thousands of streets and optimal routes, seems anachronistic in the age of GPS. However, Sutherland argues that “The Knowledge” serves a crucial function beyond mere navigation: it acts as a “commitment device” and a “reliable gauge of honest intent”. Drivers who invest such an immense amount of time and effort demonstrate “skin in the game,” making them inherently trustworthy in the eyes of passengers. This is a prime example of “costly signaling.”


This case reveals the enduring value of “unscalable” human capital in a technological age. In an era where automation and AI increasingly commoditize scalable functions, this example challenges the assumption that technological efficiency always replaces human value. “The Knowledge” creates value not just through efficient routing but through the signal of dedication and trustworthiness it conveys — a signal that GPS cannot replicate. This suggests that certain “unscalable” human investments, such as deep expertise, personal commitment, or demonstrated integrity, will retain or even increase their value as technology advances. Businesses should identify and cultivate these unique human signals of trust and quality, as they represent a distinct competitive advantage.


Richard Thaler’s Beer on the Beach


ree

Sutherland frequently references Richard Thaler’s thought experiment: people on a hot beach are asked how much they would pay for a chilled Heineken. If the beer is from a “boutique hotel” three-quarters of a mile away, people are willing to pay significantly more than if it is from a “beach shack,” even if the beer itself is identical.


This experiment vividly illustrates “transaction utility” — the perceived fairness of the price — and “acquisition utility” — the actual utility derived from the product. It demonstrates that context and expectation profoundly influence willingness to pay. This highlights the psychological elasticity of price based on context. Willingness to pay is not solely tied to the objective value of a product but is highly elastic based on the context of acquisition and perceived fairness. Consumers create an internal “reference price” based on the vendor or environment. This implies that pricing strategies should consider not just cost and objective value, but also the psychological “story” of the transaction. A higher price can be justified and even preferred if the context signals higher quality, exclusivity, or a superior experience.


US Vacation Allowance


Sutherland points to the “extraordinary case of status quo bias” evident in the “meager and pathetic” vacation allowance prevalent in the US compared to the more generous provisions in Europe. He highlights the irony that Americans often venerate retirement, viewing it as a long period of leisure, yet consider a few weeks of vacation in mid-career as “lazy”.


This example reveals the invisible hand of cultural norms on economic behavior. It demonstrates how deeply ingrained cultural norms and “status quo bias” can lead to economically suboptimal outcomes — such as less leisure time and potentially higher burnout — that are simply accepted as the norm. This suggests that “rational” economic models often fail to account for the powerful, often invisible, influence of collective beliefs and social conditioning. The implication is that changing deeply embedded behaviors requires addressing the underlying cultural narratives and psychological contracts, not just economic incentives.


Moist Lavatory Paper


In a humorous yet insightful observation, Sutherland discusses the widespread use of dry toilet paper in Western cultures and his preference for Japanese-style toilets with washing functions. He posits that the low sales of moist toilet paper might be due to “social signaling” on supermarket shelves: if dry paper dominates, moist paper appears to be for “perverts” or those with “weird medical conditions”. He proposes an experiment where supermarkets display three times as much wet paper to shift this social norm.


This lighthearted example reveals a profound truth: consumer choices, even for private acts, are heavily influenced by perceived social norms. The “default” display in a supermarket acts as a powerful signal of what is “normal” or “acceptable.” This implies that marketers and policymakers can influence behavior not just through direct messaging but by subtly altering the visible environment and perceived social consensus. It also highlights the “Somebody Else’s Problem paradox” , where a widespread, suboptimal norm persists because no one actively challenges its implicit social signal.


Women’s Fashion & Cosmetics


Sutherland delves into the motivations behind women’s spending on fashion and beauty, suggesting it extends beyond merely attracting men or engaging in status rivalry with other women. A significant aspect, he argues, is “signaling to oneself,” enabling a sense of confidence that cannot be simply willed into existence. He observes that cosmetics often need to be expensive and even cause a “borderline pain threshold thing” for the placebo effect to work, reinforcing the “I’m worth it” message.


This analysis reveals the internal psychological utility of “luxury beliefs” and personal rituals. It goes beyond external signaling to suggest that people engage in behaviors like buying expensive cosmetics not just for external validation but for internal psychological benefits. The “cost” or “pain” associated with the product enhances its perceived efficacy as a “placebo for confidence.” This suggests that a significant portion of consumer spending is driven by a desire for internal psychological states (e.g., confidence, well-being) that are achieved through ritual and belief, rather than purely functional utility. Brands can create deep value by tapping into these internal narratives and self-signaling mechanisms.


Email and Costly Signaling


Sutherland critically examines the widely held belief that email is inherently “better” simply because it is free and instantaneous. He notes that in the digital age, “information is easy to create and hard to trust”. To address the problem of information overload and the devaluation of communication, he proposes an intervention: adding a “stamp” (e.g., a $1 charitable donation) to emails to make them a “costly signal” of importance. He draws a parallel to the perceived importance of FedEx deliveries compared to standard mail. This mechanism would introduce friction to reduce “white noise” and ensure that truly important messages stand out.


This proposal highlights the paradoxical value of friction in the information age. In a world saturated with abundant, “free” information, the very ease of communication can lead to a devaluation of information and an overwhelming amount of “white noise”. Sutherland argues that strategically introducing “friction,” such as a monetary cost, can act as a “costly signal,” making communication more trustworthy and attention-worthy. This challenges the prevailing digital design philosophy of “frictionless” experiences, suggesting that carefully applied friction can enhance value, build trust, and improve the effectiveness of communication by signaling genuine intent and importance.


Red Bull’s Success


ree

The commercial triumph of Red Bull presents a compelling challenge to conventional product development and marketing logic. From a purely rational standpoint, Red Bull’s market position appears precarious: it is an expensive beverage sold in small cans, and its taste is frequently described as unpleasant. In a highly competitive beverage market, such attributes would typically predict failure. However, Red Bull’s immense success lies not in its objective qualities but in its skillful tapping into psychological factors. It cultivates a perception of exclusivity and potent energy. A key observation here is that if a product is believed to possess “medicinal or psychotropic powers,” it is often expected to “taste a bit weird”. The unpleasant taste, rather than being a deterrent, paradoxically acts as a “price” for the perceived benefit, thereby enhancing the placebo effect. This demonstrates the principle of psycho-logic, where perceived “cost” or “friction” can counter-intuitively enhance perceived value and efficacy, especially for products promising a functional benefit. This challenges the linear assumption that “more pleasant” always means “better,” suggesting that an element of “difficulty” or “sacrifice” can serve as a powerful psychological signal, making the reward feel more earned or effective.


Uber’s Map


ree

The inclusion of a real-time map showing the Uber driver’s location and estimated arrival time is a subtle yet powerful design choice. Objectively, this feature does not physically shorten the waiting time for the passenger. However, its value lies in significantly reducing psychological friction by alleviating uncertainty and providing a sense of control. Sutherland observes that “people hate uncertainty, solutions that reduce uncertainty can create a lot of value”. This exemplifies the power of psychological value and uncertainty reduction. The phenomenon illustrates that transparency, even when not directly altering a physical outcome, can provide substantial psychological utility. It transforms a passive, potentially frustrating waiting experience into an active, tolerable one, as the user feels informed and in control. This observation has broad applicability to customer service and communication strategies across industries.


Doormen vs. Automatic Doors


ree

The comparison between a human doorman and an automatic door highlights a critical distinction between efficiency and effectiveness in service delivery. Logically, an automatic door is more efficient, eliminating the salary cost of a human employee. Yet, Sutherland points out that a doorman provides multiple, often unquantifiable, psychological functions: security, status signaling, and personalized assistance, which an automatic door cannot replicate. The “waste” associated with a doorman’s salary functions as a “costly signal” of the establishment’s quality and attentiveness. This case illuminates the principles of signaling, psychological value, and intangible value. The inherent flaw in pure efficiency metrics for service industries becomes apparent here. A narrow focus on efficiency, such as cost-saving through automation, can inadvertently destroy effectiveness and value. The doorman’s contribution cannot be measured solely by throughput but by the emotional, status, and trust signals he conveys. This suggests that businesses and public services prioritizing “lean and efficient” models without considering the “jammier” human elements risk alienating customers and forfeiting intangible competitive advantages.


The “£300 Million Button”


This anecdote from e-commerce highlights the profound impact of seemingly minor design changes on user behavior and revenue. An e-commerce site experienced a dramatic increase in sales simply by changing a button label from “Register” to “Continue” and adding a line of reassuring text. This seemingly small alteration addressed significant psychological barriers that were deterring users, such as fear of commitment, privacy concerns, or the perceived effort of creating an account. This intervention effectively reduced friction in the user journey. The example demonstrates the principles of friction reduction, the power of small changes, and addressing psychological barriers. It illustrates the disproportionate impact of micro-friction on macro outcomes. Seemingly minor points of friction, often overlooked in large-scale system design, can have enormous cumulative negative effects on user behavior and revenue. The “cost” of this friction was not monetary but psychological, involving cognitive effort and anxiety. This underscores the necessity of meticulous “choice architecture” and user experience design, recognizing that human decision-making is often fragile and easily disrupted by perceived obstacles.


Sainsbury’s Potato Peeler


This example perfectly encapsulates Sutherland’s core philosophy regarding the power of perception over objective reality. When a customer complained about a potato peeler, Sainsbury’s opted for a counter-intuitive solution instead of redesigning the product, which would have been a logical but expensive fix. They simply renamed it a “carrot peeler”. This act of reframing solved the problem by altering customer expectations and perception, without any physical modification to the product itself. This case powerfully demonstrates the principles of framing, perception, and psycho-logic. It highlights the power of re-framing problems as perceptual challenges. Not all problems necessitate a physical or engineering solution; often, the “problem” resides in perception or expectation. By reframing the product’s purpose, Sainsbury’s circumvented a costly technical overhaul, proving that a psychological intervention can be a highly efficient and effective solution. This encourages a fundamental shift in problem-solving, moving from “what’s wrong with the product?” to “what’s wrong with how it’s perceived?”


Bayswater Residents Association / “Imbyism”


Sutherland draws attention to a common societal phenomenon through the case of the Bayswater Residents Association, which successfully campaigned to prevent its area from developing a vibrant nightlife. This reflects a broader tendency in Britain for collective action to “stop things happening or to keep things the same”. He contrasts this “Nimbyism” (Not In My Backyard) with the need for “Imbyism” (In My Backyard), where collective energy is harnessed to facilitate positive change. The observation is that there is a “spectacular capacity for collective action in opposing things” but a striking “inability to harness any will or consensus when it comes to doing something new”. This resistance to change often proves self-defeating, inadvertently benefiting large organizations that can navigate bureaucratic hurdles while disadvantaging smaller, traditional businesses. Sutherland proposes “Facebook democracy” for local decision-making, allowing neighbors to collectively decide what they might accept — such as a new local school, a bypass, or tax breaks — in exchange for approving development. This approach directly addresses the underlying “fear of loss of control, and fear of the irreversible”.


This example reveals the psychological roots of bureaucratic inertia and planning paralysis. The “Nimby” phenomenon is not merely selfish; it is deeply rooted in profound psychological fears of losing control and experiencing irreversible negative changes. Bureaucracies, often driven by “blame avoidance” and “slavish adherence to established procedure,” exacerbate this issue by failing to incorporate local knowledge or offer psychological “compensation” for perceived losses. This creates what Sutherland terms a “tantric sector,” characterized by endless delays and a resistance to consummation. The “Imbyism” proposal suggests that empowering local communities with a sense of control and tangible benefits can overcome this resistance, transforming a zero-sum game into a mutually beneficial outcome by addressing the underlying psychological contract.


“No one ever got fired for buying IBM”


This classic business adage serves as a powerful illustration of organizational behavior. It describes a common corporate tendency to choose the safest, most established option. Sutherland explains that this behavior is driven by “loss aversion” or “defensive decision-making” and a strong desire for “blame avoidance”. Opting for a well-known, albeit not always optimal, choice minimizes personal accountability if things go wrong. He renames this phenomenon the “Heathrow effect,” referring to the tendency to choose the default, often suboptimal, option because if it fails, blame can be attributed to the system rather than to an imaginative but riskier personal choice.


This observation highlights the perverse incentives embedded within bureaucratic decision-making. It reveals a fundamental disconnect between individual rationality (minimizing personal risk) and organizational effectiveness (optimizing overall outcomes). The “bureaucratic mindset” prioritizes “procedural neatness over end results” and “small, measurable cost-savings over effectiveness” primarily to avoid blame. This explains why large organizations often struggle with innovation: “finance and procurement departments stop you buying anything interesting, HR departments stop you hiring anyone interesting and compliance departments stop you trying anything interesting”. The implication is that organizational structures frequently reward “safe” mediocrity over potentially transformative, but riskier, innovation.


The IKEA Effect


The “IKEA Effect” refers to the phenomenon where the effort invested in assembling a product, such as IKEA furniture, increases its perceived value. Sutherland notes that IKEA’s business model partly leverages this psychological principle, as the act of assembly “destigmatizes low price”. This effect extends to other activities, such as paying more for the ritual and experience of “cutting your own Christmas tree” or “picking your own strawberries”.


This phenomenon underscores the psychological premium placed on co-creation and personal investment. It demonstrates that value is not solely inherent in a product but can be co-created through customer effort. This challenges the common assumption that convenience is always the paramount factor in consumer preference. By requiring effort, IKEA effectively transforms the customer into an “investor” in the product, increasing their psychological ownership and willingness to pay, even for items that are objectively low-cost. This has broad implications for engaging customers, fostering loyalty, and designing experiences that tap into the inherent human desire for agency and contribution.


Plastic Bag Charge


The introduction of a small charge for plastic bags in the UK led to a significant reduction in waste. Sutherland argues that even a trifling charge, such as 1p, would have been highly effective. The core observation is that “charging any amount, however trifling, was sufficient to change the implicit assumptions about normal retail behaviour”. Previously, the default was for cashiers to offer a bag; the charge shifted this default, requiring the customer to explicitly request and pay for one. Sutherland frames this as an example of the “Trump playbook,” where taxes are imposed not primarily for their direct economic effect, but for their symbolic value in shifting behavior.


This case demonstrates the transformative power of shifting implicit defaults and social scripts. It illustrates that behavioral change can be achieved not just through economic incentives but by subtly redesigning the interaction and leveraging social norms and defaults. The charge did not merely make bags costly; it fundamentally altered the social script surrounding bag usage, making it acceptable — and even expected — to not take a new bag. This implies that many societal problems can be addressed by understanding and redesigning these subtle social contracts, rather than relying solely on heavy-handed economic penalties or direct mandates.


Electric Car Sceptics (Parallel Universe)


ree

Sutherland challenges electric car skeptics by inviting them to consider a thought experiment: imagine a parallel universe where all cars are electric, and a “rogue German engineer” invents the internal combustion engine (ICE). From this inverted perspective, he highlights the “absurdity” of the ICE: its low efficiency (20% compared to 80% for electric motors), its reliance on fossil fuels, and the need for extensive external refueling stations. This “inversion mind game” reveals that many accepted technologies are only considered “logical” due to historical path dependence and a lack of comparative framing. He also notes that early electric cars were “kind of shit” before Tesla, yet people bought them for “novelty or to show off”.


This thought experiment exposes the cognitive lock-in of familiarity and highlights the value of inversion thinking. It demonstrates how familiarity can breed a form of cognitive blindness, making the irrational seem normal and the rational seem absurd. The exercise underscores the power of “inversion thinking” to break free from entrenched assumptions and reveal hidden inefficiencies or superior alternatives that are obscured by habit. The implication is that true innovation often requires not just new ideas, but a radical reframing of existing problems and solutions, challenging “unshakeably held opinions irrespective of any countervailing evidence” , which he refers to as luxury beliefs.


Restaurant World Hates Beer Drinkers / Reverse Benchmarking


Sutherland recounts an observation about a top restaurant that, despite its excellence, had two notable shortcomings: mediocre coffee and poor treatment of beer drinkers compared to wine enthusiasts. Instead of merely copying what other successful restaurants did well (“benchmarking”), this restaurant strategically focused on fixing what others in the industry did badly — a practice Sutherland terms “reverse benchmarking”. They appointed a dedicated “coffee sommelier” and a “beer sommelier”. This initiative created a “mental breakthrough” for beer drinkers, who were accustomed to being treated as “second-class citizens” in high-end establishments. This strategy led to higher differentiation, growth, and profits for the restaurant.


This case illustrates the strategic advantage of identifying and exploiting “negative externalities” in competitor offerings. While most businesses focus on improving their strengths or matching competitors’ strengths, this example demonstrates the immense value in identifying and addressing the weaknesses or negative experiences that are common across an industry. By transforming a common “pain point” — poor beer service — into a point of excellence, the restaurant generated disproportionate delight and loyalty. This suggests that competitive strategy should involve a deep dive into customer dissatisfaction with the entire market, not just direct competitors, to uncover “unserved” psychological needs. This approach fosters true differentiation and innovation, often by addressing areas neglected by the “arithmocracy” that prioritizes easily quantifiable metrics.


What’s the Point in Spending a Fortune on a Wedding?


ree


Sutherland critically examines the escalating cost of British weddings, which has risen to over £20,000 on average, without a noticeable increase in guest enjoyment. He aligns with economist Gary Stevenson’s critique of “Single Representative Agent” models in economics, which absurdly assume that what benefits the average person proportionately benefits everyone.


Sutherland observes that money spent on weddings is “competitive, not collaborative”; it creates pressure for others to spend more to “maintain appearances”. This contrasts with “cooperative” consumption, such as drinking in a pub, which provides a public good that benefits others. He likens elaborate weddings to a form of “potlatch,” a ceremonial public distribution of wealth intended to enhance social standing. This analysis reveals the societal costs of rivalrous consumption and status games. It exposes how seemingly individual choices, like wedding spending, are deeply embedded in social dynamics and can generate negative “externalities”. The “potlatch” analogy illustrates that much consumption is driven by status competition rather than pure utility, leading to an arms race where overall happiness does not necessarily increase, but costs do. This challenges simplistic economic models that assume all forms of consumption are equally valuable and highlights how “faux-rationality” in policy, such as ignoring intergenerational inequality , can perpetuate these costly social games.


How to Get Husband to do Vacuuming


ree

In a humorous yet insightful column, Sutherland discusses the “sexy hand-axe theory” from evolutionary psychology, which posits that men’s displays of technical prowess historically served as status signals in sexual selection. He applies this theory to modern household chores.


The core observation is that women can effectively encourage men to perform domestic tasks by ensuring those tasks involve “complex technology or fancy equipment”. For example, instead of explaining how to cook, one might buy Japanese knives; instead of nagging about vacuuming, one might purchase a robot vacuum cleaner. Sutherland playfully predicts an “unplanned gender revolution” where women pursue high-powered careers while men stay home, engrossed in getting smart devices to interact. This example demonstrates leveraging innate psychological drivers for behavioral change in domestic contexts. It suggests that understanding deep-seated psychological motivations, such as the male desire for technical mastery and status display, can be leveraged to influence behavior in unexpected domains. This implies that behavioral interventions can be far more successful when they tap into intrinsic human drivers rather than relying solely on extrinsic incentives or rational arguments.


BA’s New Loyalty Scheme


ree

British Airways’ decision to revise its loyalty program, shifting from a tier-point system based on flights to a “revenue-based” approach tied to spending, generated considerable “media furore”. Sutherland observes that “people who have learned to play a game by one set of rules are bitterly affronted when the rules change”. Those who perceive themselves as losing out under the new system experience a “far greater sense of outrage” than those who gain. This illustrates the powerful principles of loss aversion and status quo bias. It also highlights the inherent tension between a loyalty scheme’s corporate purpose (to encourage loyalty to BA) and customer perception (BA’s loyalty to them).


This case vividly demonstrates the asymmetric impact of gains versus losses in customer relationships. It aligns with prospect theory, showing that customers react far more strongly to the loss of perceived benefits or status than to equivalent gains. Even if the new scheme is “dispassionately… not wholly unreasonable” from a business perspective , the feeling of being unfairly treated or having the “rules of the game” changed mid-play generates disproportionate outrage. This implies that businesses must manage change with extreme care, acknowledging the psychological impact of perceived losses, even if objectively the new system is “fairer” or more efficient for the company. The “loyalty scheme” itself functions as a psychological contract, not merely a transactional one, and breaching this contract can have significant repercussions.

Comments


  • Grey LinkedIn Icon
bottom of page